WHAT OUR NATION NEEDS MOST AT THE MOMENT

Search This Blog

Saturday, May 28, 2011

Tackling food wastage : BUILD EFFICIENT SUPPLY CHAIN

Food wastage is a matter of concern and the government is still struggling for a solution. Pained by the damage last year, the Supreme Court suggested free grain distribution among the poor. Now BJP leader and former Union Food Minister Shanta Kumar wants the government to give six months’ ration to the poor in one go instead of the monthly supplies to cut the storage costs and waste. On the face of it, the idea looks attractive. However, the problem is the poor do not have the cash for bulk food purchases even at the highly subsidised rates. Secondly, those surviving on Rs 20 a day cannot be expected to spare money for storage arrangements.




In fact, even farmers are often forced to sell their entire produce to repay their debt, buy necessities or fund social ceremonies. Poverty is a hurdle. Then there is the problem of bulk transportation. The Railways is ill-equipped to meet the challenge. Grain stocks keep lying in the railway yards for months before these are moved out of Punjab, Haryana and western UP. Even the public distribution system is unable to handle large supplies. As things are, Mr Shanta Kumar’s well-meaning suggestion, it seems, is impractical but those benefiting from diversion of subsidised PDS food items would welcome it.



The Centre has appointed a committee under Planning Commission member Abhijit Sen to study the feasibility of silos under the public-private partnership model. Given the large-scale pilferage and corruption in grain handling by government agencies, there is no alternative to encouraging private investment in building efficient supply chains, including warehouses, for carrying and storing not just food grains but fruits, vegetables and other perishable items as well. Eminent economist Kaushik Basu advocates food coupons for the poor for buying ration in the open market to avoide PDS and FCI corruption. Since the proposed food law will substantially inflate the government’s food subsidy bill, there is need to put in place an efficient food management system.



A VIEW POINT....NOT OF MINE...Don’t make Lokpal a super cop

The United Nations Convention Against Corruption [2004] promotes and strengthens measures to effectively combat corruption. It supports international co-operation and technical assistance to fight corruption and helps in asset recovery. The convention also promotes integrity, accountability and proper management of public affairs and public property.




Money from corruption finances organised crime, international terrorism and drug trafficking. Corruption money is first laundered, then moved across international borders with ease to tax havens where it is difficult to reach. While in the country of its origin it is concealed income on which no tax is paid. It soon returns to the country to fuel the economy, leading to more corruption. It is an ever ending spiral.



Very few public men have been tried for possessing disproportionate assets. We have been obsessed with bribery corruption which is very local in nature. Only recently have we been taking an interest in investigating real high-end corruption of the CWG and 2G variety which has a global dimension. The previous brush with this kind of global corruption – the Bofors case – did not even go to trial because the investigation was scuttled.



We must carefully think our way through the issues of corruption and the new Jan Lokpal Bill. We need an exacting, and a precise law with a fresh set of rules and standards to judge the behaviour of public men. We need quick investigation, trial and confiscation of property. The recovery of assets must be central to the new law. The recovery of stolen assets has been singled out as a fundamental principle of the UNCAC. The World Bank has found that corruption is the single greatest obstacle against economic and social development. The UNCAC is a document of unprecedented scope and application and we must draw heavily from it in drafting the Jan Lokpal Bill. India has ratified the UNCAC after a long unexplained delay of six years.



All misconduct by public men is not corruption but all corrupt actions have an element of misconduct. Unfortunately the system neither detects nor punishes deviant behaviour. Alarm bells should sound when deviation from well-defined and publicised ethical and moral standards occurs. All public servants are expected to know and observe a high level of integrity. However, when they deviate from these standards, they escape detection. And graduate to the next level of misconduct.



Typical misconduct by public servants can be categorised in three ways: Criminal misconduct or misconduct with criminal intent, administrative misconduct and administrative lapse. Each must have a different remedy but the public servant who misconducts himself, criminally or administratively in the discharge of his official duty, must never go unpunished. Therefore, the way forward is: Prosecute criminal misconduct, departmentally award major penalty for administrative misconduct and minor penalty for administrative lapse.



Some basic principles should be clearly understood before designing the legislation to deal with corruption. A Lokpal (akin to Ombudsman) is the recipient of complaints. His work must remain confidential, never open to public. Inquiries he conducts should be confidential, names of public officials complained against, witnesses and documents examined should not be put in public domain until the Lokpal has taken a final decision. The Lokpal may find the complained act to be short of a criminal offence because it lacks criminal intent but it may all the same be administrative misconduct or lapse.



Protection for whistleblowers is essential. It will encourage people to come forward and provide information about corruption. But occasionally a public official who himself is in the dock may masquerade as a whistleblower and get protected. Care should be taken to separate pseudo whistleblowers from the real ones



On receiving the complaint and after examining and verifying its contents, the Lok Pal will have to decide the course of action, whether or not to act on the complaint. If he decides to proceed, he may send the complaint for a detailed criminal investigation which may lead to prosecution. Or the complaint may be sent to the Head of Department for departmental proceedings against the public official. If the case relates to complicated financial matters then the complaint could be sent to the CAG to carry out a special audit for detecting irregularities. For minor complaints of administrative lapses a mechanism for examining the ethical angle of the administrative action should be in place through a scheme of Ethics Commissioners.



The Lokpal too must observe a code of conduct. There is a well-recognised international Code of Ethics for Ombudsmen. The Ombudsman shall be truthful and act with integrity, shall foster respect for all members of the organisation he or she serves, and shall promote procedural fairness in the content and administration of those organisations’ practices, processes, and policies. The Ombudsman is independent in structure, function and appearance to the highest degree possible within the organisation.



While selecting the Lokpal due regard should be given to geographical distribution, gender balance and a fair representation to OBCs, SCs and STs. Do not design the Lokpal as a super cop-cum-prosecutor, or a super judge. The various clauses of the draft Lokpal Bill, 2010, empowers the Lokpal to cancel licences and leases, blacklist contractors, pass interim orders staying the implementation of decisions, transfer public servants, recommend interim relief and declare vacant post occupied by the public servant. It will have to be seen whether such orders can be passed by the Lokpal without hearing the affected party and without a provision for appeals.



The Lokpal drafting panel must ensure that the constitutional provisions of Articles 14, 21, 311 are not violated. The doctrines of judicial review, separation of powers and basic structure are respected. To pass such orders without hearing the individuals concerned would be a great travesty of justice. If the Lokpal steps into the arena of investigation and prosecution, he would be doing something that due processes of law frown upon. There could well be a constitutional clash between the Lokpal’s brief to tackle corruption and the fundamental rights of citizens. Such a legal battle would defeat the very purpose of the new Act. We need the Lokpal who function as a true ombudsman — independent, neutral, impartial, fair, just and discreet – and not as a quixotic knight in shining armour.



LITTLE BIT ON PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION

IMPORTANT THINGS TO BE KEPT IN MIND:

CREATIVITY

STYLE

CONTENT

CONTEXT

Wednesday, May 25, 2011

MY JOURNEY OF UPSC : A LIL BIT OF IT

NAME : AJAY PAL


AGE : 25 YEARS

FROM LUDHIANA

GRADUATION : DENTISTRY

AMONG TOP 10 IN STATE IN MATRIC WITH 100% MARKS IN MATHS SCIENCE AND ENGLISH

TOPPER IN LUDHIANA IN +2 MEDICAL

AMONG TOP 3 IN ALL FOUR YEARS OF BDS AS WELL AS INNOVATIVE IN INTERNSHIP..WAS CHOSEN FOR DENTSPLY PROJECT

DURING INTERNSHIP I CAME ACROSS VARIOUS PATIENTS AND FOUND THAT LAPSES ON THE PART OF ADMINISTRATION ARE TO HIGH EXTENT RESPONSIBLE FOR THE DISEASES PREVALENCE AS WELL AS LACK OF AWARENESS ON THE PART OF CITIZENS.

THEN I STARTED THINKING OF JOINING CIVIL SERVICES.THOUGH THIS IDEA WAS NOT YET CONCRETE AND I CONTINUED WITH DENTISTRY.I STARTED LEARNING OTHER WORKS IN DENTISTRY AFTER GRADUATION.BUT IN NOVEMBER 2008 I DECIDED TO BE A CIVIL SERVANT AND AROUNG NOVEMBER 25 I JOINED AN INSTITUTE IN CHANDIGARH.I STAYED THERE FOR AROUND ONE MONTH FOR PUBLIC ADMIN COACHING BUT DIDN’T FIND IT OF MUCH USE AND THEN RETURNED HOME.I SINCERELY STARTED PREPARATION AFTER MY SSC EXAMINATION i.e. 2ND MARCH AND HAD HCS PRELIMS ON 26TH APRIL.DID WORK VERY HARD AND GAINED CONFIDENCE WITH A LOT OF GUIDANCE FROM MY FATHER AND WHEN HCS PRELIMS RESULT WAS DECLARED ON MAY 3 I CLEARED AND GAINED MORE CONFIDENCE.NOW THERE WAS UPS PRELIMS ON 17 MAY AND I HAD WORKED VERY HARD AND PERFORMED GOOD IN PRELIMS AND WAS QUITE SURE OF CLEARING IT.THEN I STARTED PREPARING ZOOLOGY FOR SECOND OPTIONAL AND HAD MY HCS EXAM FROM AUGUST 22 TO SEPT 3.BUT I DIDN’T FEEL COMFORTABLE WITH ZOOLOGYU FOR UPSC SO THERE WAS LITTLE MESS ABOUT OPTIONALS FOR MY HCS AS WELL AS UPSC MAINS.I APPEARED IN HCS WITH ZOOLOGY AND PREPARED SOCIOLOGY FOR UPSC MAINS.BOTH EXAMS WENT WELL.IN THE MEAN TIME I MANAGED TO CLEAR LIC AAO (GENERALIST) EXAM AS WELL AND LATER SSC MAINS ALSO.I JOINED LIC AS AAO FOR TRAINING AT AGRA.THEN CAME RESULT OF UPSC MAINS.THOUGH STUDIED SOCIOLOGY FOR MERELY 50 DAYS APPROX BUT MANAGED TO CLEAR CIVIL SERVICES MAINS (WRITTEN) AND GOT INTERVIEW CALL.I WAS INTERVIEWED BY NAIRBHAY SIR’S BOARD.IT WENT WELL BUT CUDNT MAKE TO FINAL LIST.THEN STARTED PREPARING FOR PRELIMS AGAIN AND MANAGED TO CLEAR THAT ALONG WITH JOB IN LIC.ALSO IN MEANTIME CLEARED SSC EXAM AND MADE IT TO FINAL LIST.FOR CSE THIS TIME THOUGHT OF AGAIN CHANGING THE OPTIONAL AND TOOK PUNJABI LITERATURE.ALOT OF HELP GUIDANCE FROM FATHER I MANAGED TO COVER THE SYLLABUS.THEN APPEARED FOR CSE MAINS AND IT WENT QUITE WELL AND WAS VERY MUCH CONFIDENT OF CLEARING THE MAINS.LATER HCS MAINS RESULT WERE ALSO DECLARED IN WHICH I HAD OPTED ZOOLOGY BUT I CLEARED.AND APPEARED FOR INTERVIEW IN DECEMBER..A WEEK LATER WAS PUNJAB PCS PRELIMS WHICH I CLEARED.AND THEN GOT INTERVIEW CALL FROM UPSC FOR CSE AND THIS TIME I HAD K K PAUL BOARD KNOWN FOR NOT VERY LIBERAL MARKING.BUT DUE TO HIGH MARKS IN WRITTEN PART MANAGED TO CLEAR EXAM WITH RANK 160.

SO IT WAS QUITE A COMPLEX JOURNEY WITH LOTS OF TWISTS AND TURNS.MANY HAPPY MOMENTS AND MANY WITH LOTSA DEPRESSION.PERSONAL LIFE AND LEISURE ON BACKTRACK.ALOT OF HARD WORK.BUT IN THIS ATTEMPT AS PLANNING WAS PROPER SO COULD MANAGE WITH A DECENT RANK.

BASIC POINTS TOP BE KEPT IN MIND : HARD WORK ,CONSISTENCY,SELF MOTIVATION AND FAMILY SUPPORT.

BASIC THINGS TO BE KEPT IN MIND WHILE PREAPARING FOR CIVILS

BE CONSISTENT

DONT GET VERY PROUDY AND DONT BOOST

STAY HUMBLE

HAVE FAITH IN YOURSELF

AIM AT HIGH SPOT

AVOID THINGS THAT DIVERT YOUR MIND

KEEP URSELF CALM AND COMPOSED

Room for suspicion & concern : Well known demographer Ashish Bose questions the census figures from Punjab and Haryana

India has a proud history of uninterrupted decennial censuses ever since 1881. It is worth recalling that census data have determined the destiny of the Indian sub-continent in many ways.




The partition of India was based on census data on religion. The re-organisation of States in 1957 on a linguistic basis used census data on languages (mother-tongue). The delimitation of electoral constituencies ever since India held the first general election in 1952 is based on census data. The constituencies reserved for Scheduled Castes (SC) and Scheduled Tribes (ST) as per the Constitution of India are also based on census data.



The Finance Commission, appointed every five years under the Constitution which recommends allocation of resources between the Centre and States takes into account the population factor. So does the Planning Commission while preparing five year plans. What is not so well known is the importance of census data in formulating population policies. For example, in 1977 the Population Policy announced by the Emergency Government froze the number of seats in Parliament and State Assemblies as per 1971 census data for the next three decades. This was done to meet the demand from southern States to freeze the seats in Parliament. Otherwise, the representation of these States would have been reduced in Parliament. The comparative success of the southern states in controlling population growth and the failure of the northern states to do so has resulted in this imbalance. This had to be corrected, otherwise the number of MPs in the northern states would have gone up at the cost of the southern states. This would have meant rewarding states which failed to curb population growth.



In 2000, a National Population Policy was announced by the Government, which extended this freeze by another 25 years, i.e. up to 2026. This was given effect through a subsequent amendment to the Constitution by Parliament.



Presentation of census data



The customary way of presentation of Census data is to put all states in alphabetical order and then put the Union Territories (UTs) in alphabetical order. Later this was changed to listing states according to geographical zones like north India, north-west India and so on. Both these methods are not reader-friendly. If we are told that the decadal population growth rate of Dadra & Nagar Haveli is the highest, namely, 55.5 per cent without telling the reader at the same time that this tiny UT accounts for only 0.03 per cent of India's population, our analysis will go haywire.



In terms of size of population, there is a world of difference ranging from about 200 million (20 crores) persons in Uttar Pradesh to only 64,429 persons in Lakshadweep Islands. As we have stated earlier, mixing up all the 35 administrative units (states and UTs) regardless of their population size is misleading. We have therefore classified these 35 units into three categories as follows:



n Bigger states : population more than 10 million (1 crore),



n Smaller states/UTs: population between 1 and 10 million (10 lakh to 1 crore)



n Smallest states/UTs: population less than 1 million (10 lakhs).



The summary table is given in Table no 1



Worsening Child Sex Ratio



The most disturbing aspect of 2011 census data released so far is the growing imbalance between the sexes in the youngest age group (0-6) which is indicative of female foeticide. In short, the girl child is not wanted and therefore not allowed to be born, thanks to the use of modern medical technology.



It is interesting to note that in order to calculate the literacy rates, the age group 0-6 is excluded for obvious reasons: children don't get literate from birth. Since all Census tables give figures for total population and also separately for male and female population, the 0-6 child group figures presented data for boys and girls separately. From this one can calculate the child sex ratio or the number of girls per 1000 boys in the age group 0-6 years.



I believe that the child sex ratio (CSR) for the age group 0-6 is not the best way of finding what is happening to the girl child. A better method will be to calculate the number of girls per 1000 boys at birth. But this assumes a good system of registration of births and deaths. In spite of the legal provision for compulsory registration of births, very few people care to register births of children, especially the girl children. This is because some people think that if there is a government record of their sons, whatever the property the man has will be in government records which he can pass on to his sons, which is a mistaken notion.



The CSR has continuously declined from 976 in 1961 to 914 in 2011. It should certainly be a cause for concern to our leaders of society and the government (see Table 2 and bar chart).



The figures for variation in CSR are very perplexing. Out of the 20 bigger states, only in 4 states the CSR has increased. The greatest surprise is the jump by 48 points in Punjab and 11 points in Haryana, states which are notorious for female foeticide. This calls for evaluation of census data and also field work in Punjab and Haryana in particular. My field work in these states does not confirm that the rise in CSR is real. I hope some interested readers of The Tribune will take up this work and throw light on the accuracy of census data.



In Tamil Nadu the increase in CSR is by 4 points and in Gujarat by 3 points. In the remaining states there is a decline ranging from 82 points in Jammu & Kashmir to just 1 point in Kerala. I would not accept J&K figures as reliable in view of the disturbed condition there. It is significant that in the urbanised state of Maharashtra the decline in CSR is of the order of 30 points. Has the urban middle class taken to family planning? On the other hand, in the predominantly rural state of Rajasthan, the decline is high: 26 points. It seems that the rural masses do not want girls. So we have an odd situation where the urban middle class does not want daughters and the rural masses also do not want daughters.



I have an explanation for this which is bound to be controversial. Nevertheless let me put forward my viewpoint. We have had over 50 years of government propaganda about the need for a small family. This has certainly raised the awareness about the small family norm all over India. By small family, earlier one meant 2 or 3 children but over the years the acceptable number came down to 2 children.



For parents there are 3 possibilities: (i) 2 sons only, (ii) 2 daughters and (iii) only 1 son and 1 daughter. The second scenario is the worst. The cost of dowry and marriage has gone up. We are becoming increasingly a consumerist society. Greed has overtaken need. One cannot order a small family with only 2 sons or for that matter, 1 son and 1 daughter, unless one takes recourse to medical intervention or in simple language, finding out the sex of the unborn child and taking to abortion if it is a female child. The government enacted the PCPNDT Act quite sometime back, which prohibits such medical intervention but it is well known that its implementation is very poor. Will the CSR go down further in next census of 2021?


Reform food policy to contain prices

Spikes in food and fuel prices in 2008 caused inflation rates to increase in most Asian countries. With the onset of the global financial crisis in 2008-09, however, price pressures subsided rapidly across the region except in South Asia. Indeed, India and Pakistan are experiencing double-digit inflation driven mainly by food.




Given the high incidence of poverty in the region, higher food and overall inflation rates disproportionately affect the poor. Moreover, because of the large share of food in the average household consumption budget, a sustained rise in food prices tends to put upward pressure on wages and, with a time lag, on general inflation.



An analytical and empirical examination of the causative factors of inflation can be divided broadly into two categories: demand and supply. The analysis shows that demand components have tended to fluctuate with output levels and growth rates but they have not been major independent sources of price shocks. The major sources of price volatility have been from the supply side.



Although longer-run aggregate supply in South Asian countries is elastic given youthful populations in transition to more productive occupations, it is subject to frequent negative supply shocks. Demand contractions tend to amplify these shocks. South Asian economies are supply constrained in the sense that while output is largely determined by demand, inefficiencies on the supply side tend to perpetuate inflation by creating shortages of goods and services from time to time.



Food price-wage cycle



With a supply shock, the aggregate supply curve in the figure shifts upward, leading to higher inflation. If, in response, a demand contraction shifts the aggregate demand curve downward, this reduces inflation only marginally and at a high cost in terms of output lost. Therefore, the use of restrictive demand-side policies to tackle inflation when its causes are primarily on the supply side may not help much in reducing overall inflationary pressures. Both formal econometric tests and analysis of shock episodes based on Indian data support this analysis.



In South Asia the food price-wage cycle is an important mechanism for propagating price shocks and creating inflationary expectations in response to a supply shock, which acts as an inflation trigger. The political economy of farm price support, consumption subsidies and wage support, with built-in waste, inefficiencies and corruption, contributes to chronic cost-push pressures. Poor targeting of consumption subsidies implies nominal wages rising with a time lag, pushing up costs and generating second-round inflationary pressures from a temporary supply shock.



The political economy of the sub-region informally indexes wages with food price inflation. If the rise in average wages exceeds that of agricultural productivity, however, prices of food will inevitably go up, propagating more generalised inflation. Populist policies that provide short-term subsidies but raise indirect costs also contribute to cost-push pressures. For example, neglected infrastructure and poor public services increase overall costs in the economy. The power shortages from which most South Asian countries suffer are a case in point.



Virtually all countries in the sub-region have shifted to more flexible exchange rates that are managed to varying degrees. Bangladesh and Sri Lanka avoided significant exchange rate depreciation during the global crisis and their inflation rates dropped into the low single digits in 2009. Elsewhere, however, food inflation has remained high. These differential outcomes indicate a more strategic use of exchange rates in anti-inflation policy.



Once the nature and structure of shocks and elasticities of aggregate demand and supply are identified, certain policy implications follow: a shift down the supply curve in response to a supply shock; avoidance of an excessively large demand contraction; and the identification and removal of propagation mechanisms. Above all, a hasty tightening of monetary policy will, in all likelihood, involve a large output cost with little effect on inflation.



Policy options



Mild but early monetary tightening after a supply shock can prevent inflationary wage expectations from becoming entrenched and further pushing up the supply curve. Given this, a first-round price increase from a supply shock might be allowed, but a second-round wage-price increase should be prevented inasmuch as possible. A nominal appreciation of the exchange rate can serve to push down the supply curve.



Short-term fiscal policies to push down the supply curve include tax and tariff cuts and freer imports. These policies can also lower inflationary expectations. Trade policy works best for individual country shocks that are not globally correlated. Nimble private trade can defeat speculative hoarders. It should be stressed that short-run policies are likely to work only for a temporary shock. A long-lasting shock requires a longer-term productivity response.



Food prices play a central role in propagation mechanisms since they raise nominal wages with a time lag. A fundamental reason for chronic supply-side inflation is that real wages tend to exceed labour productivity. The solution is to raise labour productivity, especially in agriculture.



Following liberalisation, as farm produce has become part of the wider traded economy, global prices have begun to affect domestic food prices. In such a situation, the exchange rate can affect food prices and overall inflation. Conflict between a depreciated exchange rate to encourage exports and an appreciated exchange rate to increase real wages can contribute to a wage-price cycle, with depreciation raising nominal wages and prices and leading to real appreciation. Attempts to dampen exchange rate appreciation sustain the cycle. Only improvements in productivity can close the demand-supply gap and break this inflation propagation mechanism.



Capital inflows will tend to appreciate the exchange rate, thus satisfying the wage target, and finance the accompanying rise in imports. But a widening current account deficit is risky even though it might allow gross investment to exceed domestic savings. It would be preferable to set a sustainable current account deficit and meet it by raising productivity in the economy. Rising productivity increases the level of capital inflows that can be safely absorbed at a reasonable current account deficit. In this regard, better governance and improved delivery of public services improve productivity in the economy and, within the corpus of governance, reform of food policy is especially urgent given the economy-wide impact of food inflation.



Governance in food policy



Developing East Asian countries with large food components in household budgets have successfully moderated food inflation by focusing on raising agricultural productivity. India moved early to agricultural subsidies together with implicit taxes generated through the imposition of restrictions on different activities within the agricultural sector, including public distribution schemes.



Procurement prices were raised with the rise in border prices but did not fall with them, thus imparting generalised cost-push pressures in the economy and creating unnecessarily large food stocks in costly and dysfunctional food support programmes. If the procurement price becomes a true support price, food stocks should come down in a bad agricultural season when market prices rise and go up as market prices fall in a good year. Through such a policy, farmers would receive some assured income support even as a removal of restrictions on the movement and marketing of agricultural goods and better infrastructure allowed them to diversify their crops.



With lower average stocks, the public distribution scheme should focus more on remote, inaccessible areas. Food coupons or cash transfers directed primarily to female members of households can provide food security to the poor while allowing them to diversify their food consumption basket. Since the income elasticity of demand for food is still high, more moderate nominal price increases could serve to incentivize higher agricultural output and income growth.



Political jostling when deciding on food policy, in general, and procurement prices, in particular, ignores their negative long-term effects. Poor coordination means that multiple agencies do not factor in each other's costs or consider the wider picture. Until thorough food policy reform occurs, a possible nominal appreciation of the nominal exchange rate can prevent a sharp rise in border prices from triggering multiple interest group actions resulting in complex domestic distortions.



Managing supply shocks



Emerging markets must find non-distortionary ways to respond to spikes in food and commodity prices. Large global spikes imply distortions beyond supply shocks, which should be prevented. Policies that are driving up prices across all asset categories such as excessive liquidity creation in some of the developed countries that is directing large funds into commodities, might be re-examined at a sub-regional or regional level and its impact modified through some form of collective action.



Futures markets help output planning through better information on future demand and supply and the hedging of risk, but any overreaction implies that prices in financial markets do not reflect their real determinants. The answer is not to ban such markets but to improve their working and regulation. Progressive convergence towards common global regulatory standards can prevent arbitrage. Participation by more diverse groups in commodity trading could be encouraged within a framework of rules that discourage market abuses and thereby limit volatility.

RANK 3 ..MR.VARUN

ESSAY   119

GEN STUDY    115 +123
SOCIOLOGY   366
PUB ADMIN   360
INTERVIEW  234
WRITTEN TOTAL 1083
TOTAL  1317

TOPPER'S MARKS

RANK 1
ESSAY 114

GENERAL STUDIES   151+114

LAW                       374

PUBLIC ADMIN     191+ 165

INTERVIEW               225

WRITTEN TOTAL    1109
TOTAL                        1334

MY MARKS

ESSAY                                        110

PUBLIC ADMIN                        177+141

PUNJABI LIT                             176+166

GENERAL STUDIES                 155+113

INTERVIEW                                     162

WRITTEN TOTAL           1038

TOTAL                             1200